Skip to main content

Introduction

Economic incentives in occupational safety and health (OSH) describe processes that reward organisations for safe and healthy workplaces. From a European perspective, incentives are seen as an effective tool complementary to OSH regulation aimed at encouraging businesses at the management level to provide good OSH. Tax or insurance premium reductions are common examples. A range of economic incentive schemes can be classified along two lines: First, according to the source issuing the incentive, i.e., public governmental authorities or workers’ compensation insurers, and second, according to the mode of operation, i.e., result-based or effort-based incentives. Below, the most commonly applied external financial incentive schemes are explained in further detail.

Policy-related governmental economic incentives

Public authorities primarily use two complementary policy instruments to promote OSH at the workplace. First, they may use the enforcement of OSH regulations and experience rating of workers’ compensation insurance premiums (see below). Other financial incentive schemes which may be employed by governments include taxes (or tax reductions) and , matching funds and the linkage of financial revenues to audits or intervention programmes[1].

Enforcement strategies for OSH regulation

Although OSH regulations do not fall under a strict definition of “economic incentives", they are designed to influence the behaviour of the involved parties and, thus, they provide the framework for economic incentive schemes. The EU-OSHA overarching review on Improving compliance with occupational safety and health regulations[2] includes an overview of external institutional support for securing compliance with OSH regulation and better OSH practice. In terms of enforcement strategies, the report indicates that there are strong differences between the Member States since they determine and implement arrangements according to their national political, social and economic contexts. This leads to significant variation in priority setting and resource allocation, in programmes and interventions, and in how inspection and enforcement are conducted[2]. However, research suggests that OSH legislation and workplace inspections (with or without penalties) are effective means to improve the safety and health in workplaces[3]

Taxes

Governments also can try to stimulate companies to engage in OSH preventative measures by utilizing taxes. Taxes can be used either to punish poorly performing firms or as a positive incentive. However, the latter, the use of tax reductions as a reward is more common. For example, a Swedish commission proposed the reduction of taxes for organisations that provide physical and cultural activities at the workplace1. Further, tax breaks could be offered to companies that perform well as an incentive to improve workplace safety and health. However, tax breaks are not easy to enact and are costly due to the additional administrative burden they create. Furthermore, they are applicable only to companies that pay corporate taxes and that make a taxable profit. Also, companies only realise their profits at the end of a fiscal year. Public and non-profit sector organisations will not benefit from this type of economic incentive.

Matching funds

A matching fund is an incentive scheme that offers public grants in proportion to the amount of money the company spends on workplace safety and health, i.e. for every euro spent by the organisation, the government grants one euro. The Austrian FGÖ (Fonds Gesundes Österreich) is an example. It supports and funds projects in the fields of health promotion and primary prevention. Companies of all sizes can take part by filling in a project template. Only projects meeting the quality criteria and focusing on the longer term are eligible[4]
Another example is a subsidy programme in Andalusia aimed at replacing non-compliant scaffolding in the construction sector. In the framework of the programme, grants were awarded to companies investing in new and compliant scaffolding. The number of participating companies was estimated at 5% of the registered SMEs in the construction sector. Overall, the subsidy policy has led to a 71% decrease of accidents involving falls to a lower level in the companies which received grants in the period 2009-2011 [5].

Linking economic incentives to audits or intervention programmes

This incentive system links audits or intervention programmes to financial grants in an effort to stimulate good OSH behaviour by firms. For instance, in Canada, firms can sign up for annual OSH audits and economic incentives of up to two million US dollars are handed out to organisations with outstanding results[1].

Insurance-related economic incentives

Insurance-related economic incentive schemes usually are designed to change the behaviour of employers and employees mainly with respect to two moral hazard problems. The first is the so-called risk-bearing moral hazard, meaning that workers will pay less attention to their health and safety if they know that they are covered by workers’ compensation insurance. The second is the claims-reporting moral hazard, meaning that workers’ compensation benefits may increase the probability that workers will report claims that they would not report if there were no or lower compensation benefits[1]. Workers compensations and its role in prevention In an effort to solve these two moral hazard problems and to make employers aware of their true production costs (including the costs of work-related accidents and illnesses), insurance premiums are frequently linked to OSH performance indicators (accident or disease rates) International comparison of occupational accident insurance system. One generally can distinguish between result-based incentives and effort-based incentives that reward good OSH behaviour. The most commonly applied form of insurance-related result-based incentive designed to stimulate good OSH behaviour by enterprises is experience rating of workers’ compensation insurance[1]. Below, a variety of forms and examples of experience-rating schemas are explained in more detail.

Experience rating of workers’ compensation insurance

Workers’ compensation insurers primarily apply different forms of experience rating in an effort to solve the claims-reporting moral hazard. Experience rating is a method of determining the price of premiums for different groups or individuals based on claims history rather than accident experience. As a result, the employer is stimulated to engage in claims prevention as well as accident and illness prevention. In short, an individual's or group’s historic data is used as a proxy for future risk, and insurers adjust and set insurance premiums and plans accordingly. There are a number of variations of experience-rating in practice, including bonus-malus systems or premium assessment rates, designed to stimulate good OSH behaviour[6][7][8]

Bonus-malus systems

A bonus-malus system rewards companies that have performed well with lower premiums and punishes poorly-performing ones with higher premiums. Usually a bonus-malus ladder with a number of assembly levels (15-20) is employed. Each level provides a discount or an extra amount to the premium. Following a year without claims, the insured party climbs one level on the ladder. Car insurance premiums are a common example. Many countries apply bonus-malus systems within there workers’ compensation insurance to promote OSH management. Examples are the German food and catering sector (BGN) where a bonus malus system is in place to reward prevention efforts[9] and the Accident Insurance Association (AAA) in Luxemburg[10].  

Premium assessment rates

Premium assessment rates require a two-step procedure[11] . First, a base rate is calculated comparing the company to the industrial classifications of groups sharing the same risks for occupational injury or illness. Second, the base premium rate can be adjusted per company within a group based on its individual past safety record (experience-rating). This two-step method is more flexible than ordinary experience rating, in which all enterprises within a rate category pay the same premium regardless of the injury records of individual firms.

Partial insurance

Partial insurance is another feature of workers’ compensation which might reduce the moral hazard effect on employees. In general, partial insurance refers to any type of insurance that omits certain risks or only covers costs in specific circumstances. The common meaning of partial insurance is incomplete insurance coverage, i.e., leaving out certain areas of coverage while other areas are covered. With respect to workers’ compensation, partial insurance implies waiting periods and wage replacement rates for employees and offers newer, deductible insurance contracts for employers[1].

Key aspects and success factors of economic incentives

Despite the absence of large-scale empirical evidence, the use of insurance-related economic incentives such as experience-rating of workers’ compensation premiums or partial insurance in addition to OSH regulation seem to be an effective way to motivate enterprises to undertake preventive OSH measures. In addition to incentives relating to workers’ compensation, incentives such as reductions in employers’ liability insurance premiums, which represent a considerable expense for firms, also could be a strong motivator for managers to invest in occupational safety and health measures.

When it comes to the design of economic incentives for workers’ compensation insurance, three key aspects must be considered[12]:

  • Because many parties are involved in the workers’ compensation system, the system itself has to be reliable. If not, the whole process is at risk of being derailed;
  • Economic incentives must be developed in such a manner that technical and social feasibility is guaranteed (the design of tariffs can be particularly sensitive);
  • The credibility of workers’ compensation insurance will be weakened if the economic incentive system is subject to many changes in a short period.

In conclusion, the following seven factors are necessary for economic incentives to be efficient and successful[1]:

  • In addition to past good OSH performance, specific prevention efforts should be rewarded by the economic incentive scheme in an effort to reduce future accidents and ill-health;
  • The economic incentive scheme should be open to companies of all sizes and should account for the special needs of SMEs;
  • The value of the financial incentive should provide a true motivation for employers;
  • The relationship between the desired prevention activity and the reward should be directly visible and clear to an enterprise;
  • The economic incentive system’s award criteria should be clear and as easy as possible to apply in an effort to keep the administrative burden as low as possible;
  • If the economic incentive targets a large number of enterprises, insurance or tax-based incentives with precisely defined criteria are the most effective (a closed system);
  • If the economic incentive is aimed at promoting innovative solutions for specific areas, subsidy schemes are the most effective (an open system).

References

[1] EU-OSHA – European Agency for Safety and Health at Work. Economic incentives to improve occupational safety and health: a review from the European perspective. Report, 2010. Available at: https://osha.europa.eu/en/publications/economic-incentives-improve-occupational-safety-and-health-review-european-perspective

[2] EU-OSHA – European Agency for Safety and Health at Work. Improving compliance with occupational safety and health regulations: an overarching review. Report, 2021. Available at: https://osha.europa.eu/en/publications/improving-occupational-safety-and-health-changing-world-work-what-works-and-how 

[3] Andersen, J. H., Malmros, P., Ebbehoej, N. E., Flachs, E. M., Bengtsen, E., & Bonde, J. P. (2019). Systematic literature review on the effects of occupational safety and health (OSH) interventions at the workplace. Scandinavian journal of work, environment & health, 45(2), 103-113.

[4] Fonds Gesundes Österreich. Available at: https://fgoe.org/projektfoerderung_ueberblick

[5] Rubio-Romero, J. C., Carrillo-Castrillo, J. A., & Gibb, A. (2015). Prevention of falls to a lower level: evaluation of an occupational health and safety intervention via subsidies for the replacement of scaffolding. International journal of injury control and safety promotion, 22(1), 16-23.

[6] Tompa, E., Trevithick, S., McLeod, C., 'A systematic review of the prevention incentives of insurance and regulatory mechanisms for occupational health and safety', Scandinavian Journal of Work, Environment and Health, Vol 33 No 2, 2007, pp. 81 - 95

[7] Thomason, T., 'Economic incentives and workplace safety', in F. Sullivan (ed), ‘Preventing and managing disability injury at work’, Taylor and Francis Incorporated, 2003, pp. 183-202.

[8] Durbin, D., Butler, R.J. 'Prevention of disability from work-related sources: the roles of risk management, government intervention, and insurance', in T. Thomason, J. F. Burton, D.E. Hyatt (eds) ‘Systematic Occupational Health and Safety Management, Pergamon, 2000, pp. 227-246.

[9] BGN. Das neue Beitragsausgleichsverfahren (BAV) der Berufsgenossenschaft Nahrungsmittel und Gastgewerbe (BGN) Erläuterungen, 2020. Available at: https://www.bgn.de/mitgliedschaft-beitrag/beitrag/beitragsausgleichsverfahren/Broschuere_BAV_2020.pdf 

[10] AAA - Association d'assurance accident. Système bonus-malus. Available at: https://aaa.public.lu/fr/prestations-cotisations/cotisations/bonusmalus.html

[11] Mustard, C. 'Cooperation between insurance and prevention’, Safety Science Monitor, Vol 9, No 1, 2005, pp. 1-11.

[12] Munich Re Group 'Economic incentives. A reflection on workers’ compensation systems’, Discussion paper prepared by the Centre of Competence for workers’ compensation, No 2, November 2005, pp. 1-11.

Further reading

EU-OSHA – European Agency for Safety and Health at Work. Economic incentives to improve occupational safety and health: a review from the European perspective’. Report, 2010. Available at: https://osha.europa.eu/en/publications/economic-incentives-improve-occupational-safety-and-health-review-european-perspective 

EU-OSHA – European Agency for Safety and Health at Work. Improving compliance with occupational safety and health regulations: an overarching review. Report, 2021. Available at: https://osha.europa.eu/en/publications/improving-occupational-safety-and-health-changing-world-work-what-works-and-how

EU-OSHA – European Agency for Safety and Health at Work. How to create economic incentives in occupational safety and health: A practical guide’. Report, 2011. Available at: https://osha.europa.eu/en/publications/how-create-economic-incentives-occupational-safety-and-health-practical-guide

EU-OSHA – European Agency for Safety and Health at Work. Cost-benefit-analysis of economic incentives at national level. E-fact 50, 2010. Available at: https://osha.europa.eu/en/publications/e-fact-50-cost-benefit-analysis-economic-incentives-national-level 

Select theme

Contributor

Gerard Zwetsloot

John Klein Hesselink

Daniela Treutlein

Karla Van den Broek

Prevent, Belgium